In a world wracked with crises of confidence in the capital
markets, I am puzzled by the dereliction of accountability in the realm of advocates,
“independent” rating agencies, and advisors.
In his critical inquiry written in 2009, Université de Montréal’s Professor Stéphane Rousseau
details the extensive contribution Credit Rating Agencies had in the conditions
leading to the Global Financial Crisis of 2007-2008. While rating agencies wilfully ignored
evidence of credit quality erosion in favor of propping up phony investment
grade ratings on financial products, they have borne no meaningful liability
for the catastrophic effects of their neglect.
And while Rousseau and others comment on the massive financial harm done
by this market failure, he provides little evidence to suggest that meaningful
steps will be taken to address the massive conflicts of interest or user
complicity in the environment that creates a dearth of comprehensive
transparency.
Now it
doesn’t take a degree in economics to figure out that issuer-pays models of
credit rating have an inherent conflict.
If investors were truly free to opt in or out of purchasing “investment
grade” products, for example, then competition for asset quality may be a countervailing
force to hold rating efforts in check.
However, in a world where pensions, insurance companies, banks, and
other asset managers are required to hold assets with certain ratings, the
notion that there is a market force to hold originators or raters accountable
is laughable. Furthermore, with central
banks and sovereigns complicit in issuing bonds that need to preserve the
illusion of being “safe”, the ability for true qualitative rating to flourish
is a phantasmal illusion.
But here’s
the trouble with trying to solve the honest broker problem: the public is passively or wilfully ignorant
of basic financial literacy and thereby neither knows the questions to ask nor
the ability to discern the veracity of the answers provided by ‘experts’.
Let me
offer a few examples.
A country
just announced that it is investing public funds into the development of a
mining operation within its borders. It
is investing about $120 million into a project – not the publicly traded
company allegedly running the project.
For its $120 million, it stands to receive (according to the optimistic interpretation
of the agreement) 30% of the economics of the project (an unincorporated joint
venture) – not equity in the publicly traded holding company. During the same time the country was being encouraged
to use public funds to invest in the JV, the company raised about ¼ of the
amount in an issuance of commons shares for which one of its largest
shareholders received a fee of C$2 million.
That’s right, a shareholder got paid to invest in common equity while
the country from whom resources will be taken was told to pay for the privilege
of getting a minority stake in the venture.
Now, the kicker is the following.
It would be reasonable to expect that a 30% stake of a venture sold for
$120 million would mean that the venture must be worth about $400 million,
right? Wrong. Contemporaneous with the country’s
investment, the public markets priced the entire
corporation at $224 million. Oh, and
another point. When the public company
bought the license to the project it claims to be worth around $400 million, it
paid about $13 million in 2006. Since
then, it’s lost nearly $90 million with no reasonable revenue on the horizon. Is the company’s auditor
PricewaterhouseCoopers to blame for this perplexing market-defying
transaction? Probably not. Is the country’s finance minister or asset
manager to blame for getting terms far worse than the company’s own
shareholders? Probably not. Is the company preying on market ignorance
within the country? Absolutely. Would the country or the company’s auditor
make different decisions if they were informed of all the facts? Most certainly.
A high net
worth investor has close to $1 billion.
For years, his assets have been the siren for “asset managers” and “private
wealth managers”. Using hundreds of
pages of charts, graphs and disclaimers, investment professionals have desperately
tried to convince him – for a fee – to allocate funds to partnerships that
promise returns or market risk mitigation.
And, once allocated, performance has not matched the modeled returns. Their explanations are reminiscent of
cartoons depicting court advisors and astrologers who express their interpretations
of omens and entrails with sufficient generalities to explain either accuracy
or fallacy with equal confidence. All
the while, quantifiable risk and return, a measurable (and measured) phenomenon,
is ignored in the clamor of professional opinions and explanations. The illusion of brand credential costs this
investor at least $10 million each quarter (for which he pays a few hundred
thousand dollars) but is never explicitly recognized. Is the investor’s staff culpable for this
lost performance? Probably not. Should the principal be an expert in all
global investment products? Probably
not. Are the paid advisors preying on
the product and performance ignorance of the investor? Absolutely.
Would the investor and his staff make different decisions if they were
fully informed of all the facts? Most
certainly.
In both of
the examples above, the common denominator of predatory abuse is one party’s
willingness to exploit a lack of knowledge while all those being abused are
kept in the mists of uncertainty and ignorance.
In both of the examples above, the damaged parties have been informed of
the wilful harm perpetrated on them and, in both examples, they have been
incapable of responding due to the perception that, in the absence of their own
competence or qualifications, it’s safer to go with a branded name than
becoming fully informed and acting in enlightened self-interest.
Which leads
me to a rather important question. Why
is it that ‘victims’ of financial abuse are willing to expose themselves to
predators even when fully informed of the harm they’ll face? Whether its pension managers, resource-laden
countries, or high net worth investors, the ‘honest broker’ is rejected in
favor the consensus predator promoter. Post-2008
no rating agency suffered Arthur Andersen’s post-Enron criminal fate. Why?
Because their patrons still are benefiting from their dubious
negligence. Following decades of “resources
curse” awareness heads of state and finance ministries still fall for the same
illiquid ‘partnership’ deals that let public investors enrich themselves while
countries are rife with poverty and corruption.
Why? Because intimidation of
power by corporate and capital elite is more powerful than the will of leaders
to defend their citizens. Despite
persistent non-performance and sub-par performance, high net worth individuals
continue to cede their stewardship to proven incompetence. Why? Because
wealth, beyond manageable measure, debilitates those who confidently made
it. And in any of these eco-systems,
where is the truth welcome? Regrettably,
nowhere.
But in each
of these cases, it is my contention that the problem actually arises from a
deeper paradox. Those who don’t welcome
the truth may merely be evidencing a deep insecurity into the nature of why
they’re sitting on such excessive opportunity.
The pension manager may be overwhelmed with the sense of responsibility to
those whose funds are entrusted to him or her.
The head of state may be ill-equipped to steward the resources within a
nation’s border. The financially wealthy
may doubt their entitlement to the excess that a market transaction placed in
their hands. In each of these instances,
the rejection of transparency, truth and honesty may be a protection against
the ultimate truth that cannot be confronted – that the steward suffers from a
sense of inadequacy or confidence.
Therefore, one of the great opportunities facing those who value
transparency and ethical, accountable markets, may be to care for and engage
the steward, not the perceived asset, and in so doing, emancipate them from the
burden of inordinate, unwelcome responsibility.
Maybe we need a bit less empirical honesty and a bit more compassionate
collaboration with those to whom much has been entrusted.